Skip to main content

Tax Claims in Transnational Insolvencies: A "Revenue Rule" Approach

Editor's Note: The following article, "Tax Claims in Transnational Insolvencies: A 'Revenue Rule' Approach," won the prize for third place in the Second Annual ABI Bankruptcy Law Student Writing Competition. The article discusses issues that arise when a multi-national company files for bankruptcy, specifically when a government attempts to collect taxes from a bankrupt company that files in a foreign country. The author, Jonathan M. Weiss, is a student at UCLA Law School. In addition to recognition and publication of his article in the Bankruptcy Litigation Committee Newsletter, Mr. Weiss receives a cash award of $500 and a one-year ABI membership.

The ABI Bankruptcy Law Student Writing Competition was headed by the Hon. Judith K. Fitzgerald of the U.S. Bankruptcy Court for the Western District of Pennsylvania. Judge Fitzgerald is the Special Projects/Task Force Leader for the Bankruptcy Litigation Committee and was assisted by the committee leadership and members of the committee.

Introduction:
The past decade has brought several insolvencies of large, multinational corporations.[1] While insolvencies in the United States are neatly governed by title 11 of the United States Code, when foreign assets become involved, a conflict-of-laws problem quickly arises[2] as each country has its own, often very different, laws governing insolvency.[3]The “disparities in and, in some cases, conflicts between national laws have created unnecessary obstacles to the achievement of the basic economic and social goals of insolvency proceedings.”[4] For example, suppose that ABC Corporation, operating in both the United States and in Canada, files for bankruptcy in the United States.  Canadian lenders, employees, and the Canadian government all file claims in the U.S. bankruptcy case.  How are they to get paid, if at all?  This paper will discuss that, although lenders, employees, and most other foreign creditors will be paid, a problem arises when foreign governments file tax claims, expecting to be paid from a bankruptcy proceeding in a different country.  Because of an old doctrine known as the “revenue rule," countries are loathe to assist their neighbors in collecting taxes, and this lack of enforcement creates problems in both the bankruptcy and tax arenas.

As background, it is important to understand the four approaches to administering transnational insolvencies.  The first two approaches are pure universalism and modified universalism.[5]  Pure universalism maintains that all of a multinational corporation’s assets, wherever they may be located, must be pooled together.[6]   Those assets are then administered in a single proceeding, in the debtor’s home country and under its laws, with the rulings being effective worldwide.[7]  Modified universalism, an outgrowth of pure universalism, is similar to pure universalism in that the assets of the debtor are pooled together and administered by one court, but allows individual countries to evaluate the fairness of that proceeding, and to open their own local proceedings if necessary.[8]   The second two approaches are pure territorialism and cooperative territorialism.[9]  Pure territorialism, is a “land-grab” approach, and argues that each nation should exercise control over the assets within its borders.[10]    No foreign deference is required, as each country applies its own laws to the assets within its jurisdiction.[11]  Lastly, cooperative territorialism maintains separate proceedings in each country, but encourages cooperation between nations through protocols “on an as-needed basis,” and resolves some matters by the use of “international conventions.”[12]  

Emerging from the debate is a clear sense of the dominance of universalism.[13]   The United Nations proposed a “Model Law” of universalist guidelines to govern transnational insolvencies.[14]  The European Union has adopted universalist rules governing the transnational insolvencies of its member nations.[15]   Finally, the United States, in 2005, adopted the Model Law as the new Chapter 15 of the Bankruptcy Code to replace section 304, which had allowed for permissive recognition, but which resulted in unpredictable inconsistencies due to excessive judicial discretion.[16]  While universalism does offer increased predictability and efficiency, as explained below, those benefits are muted by the lack of enforcement with respect to foreign tax claims. 

The Problem: Foreign Tax Claims
The universalist scheme works well only with private law claims, such as those of banks or trade creditors.[17]   For example, if, in a bankruptcy case filed in the United States, a Canadian bank files a claim, the U.S. court will likely accept that claim.  However, acquiescence to foreign authority does not work well with public law claims, such as tax claims.[18]  For example, if, in the same case, the Canadian government files a claim for unpaid taxes, that claim is unlikely to be allowed by United States courts[19].  The American Law Institute’s Transnational Insolvency Project, in avoiding handling the problem of tax priorities, stated that “[t]he granting of priority to domestic tax claims in multinational cases will remain a serious problem.”[20]  The drafters of the Model Law expressed similar reservations, allowing complete discrimination and disallowance of foreign tax claims.[21]  Consider ABC Corporation doing business in Country X and Country Y, with the COMI being in Country X.  Suppose that the laws of Country X mandate universalism, which treats local and foreign tax claims similarly, and that Country X gives a high priority to tax claims.[22]  Suppose further that Country Y’s government has filed a tax claim, expecting to be paid according to Country X’s priority (i.e. “cross priority”).[23]  Should the tax claim be paid?  What if Country Y is regarded as a rogue nation which files illegal tax claims to exert corrupt political pressure?  Alternatively, suppose that Country Y is law-abiding but imposes a 75% tax on its corporations.  The ALI and Model Law do not deal with the question of whether cross-priority should be granted to tax claims, and at present, countries do not enforce such claims.[24]  This lack of enforcement of foreign tax claims presents a major problem for transnational insolvency scholars, particularly those who favor the universalist approach.  Thus, by examining the doctrine behind the refusal to enforce foreign tax claims, we can craft solutions which will fully realize the benefits of universalism by allowing for cross-priority of foreign tax claims. 

The Revenue Rule
The revenue rule, which mandates that no country should recognize the tax claims of another country, originated in England in the 1700s.[25]  It was adopted into United States law by the Court of Appeals for the Ninth Circuit in Her Majesty the Queen ex rel. British Columbia v. Gilbertson,[26] which involved an attempt by the government of British Columbia to enforce a tax on citizens of Oregon who had performed logging work in Canada.[27]  The Ninth Circuit upheld the District Court’s holding denying enforcement of the tax claims.[28]  Other countries have also refused to enforce foreign tax claims on similar grounds.[29]   There are numerous justifications for not enforcing foreign tax claims.[30]  First, Judge Learned Hand posited that requiring countries to enforce tax claims of their neighbors would require some analysis of the tax claim, and could be embarrassing to the foreign state.[31]  Additionally, United States courts may not be able to understand, evaluate, and enforce tax claims of other nations.[32]   Furthermore, supporters of the revenue rule approach argue that national sovereignty is threatened when countries satisfy foreign tax claims, against national assets, which could have strengthened the home government or its economy.[33]  Lastly, supporters of the revenue rule approach argue that, if the United States were to enforce foreign tax claims, the initiative would have to come from the executive branch, and not from the judiciary.[34]  

Despite these concerns, there would be acknowledged benefits from mutual enforcement of foreign tax claims, in contravention of the revenue rule.[35]  First, it would obviously benefit the notion of international comity, as countries would be able to cooperate and exchange information with one another.  Second, it would support the notion of justice, as tax evaders would be forced to pay their debt, and wouldn’t be allowed to shirk this obligation solely due to geographic location.  Finally, it would benefit nations as a whole, as each person would pay his or her fair share of the national tax burden.[36]  Thus, there would clearly be benefits to nations from abrogating the revenue rule, and enforcing foreign tax claims.  In addition, the enforcement of foreign tax claims would further promote bankruptcy policy under a universal scheme, as discussed below.

Three Potential Solutions:
Solution A:  The best possible solution, from both a bankruptcy and a tax perspective, would be to unilaterally mandate universal cross-priority for foreign tax claims.  While not abrogating the revenue rule completely, such a mandate would create a “bankruptcy exception,” through which the revenue rule is not recognized in the context of a transnational insolvency, and foreign tax claims are enforced.[37]  Thus, for example, in a bankruptcy case in the United States, a foreign government’s tax claim would be completely allowed and paid, just like a tax claim by the United States government.  Although, at first, this seems to be an overly ambitious and broad suggestion—since foreign tax claims have never been recognized—it is this author’s contention that, when dealing solely within the bankruptcy context, this solution ameliorates the policy concerns that the revenue rule approach had addressed, and achieves tax policy goals, which, when combined with bankruptcy policy goals, make this a clear choice as the best possible approach.  First, in terms of bankruptcy goals, this approach is the ultimate “ex ante” solution.  The United States would be unilaterally telling corporations, investors, and foreign governments, before any relationships or obligations are entered into, that foreign tax claims will be recognized in an insolvency case.  Obviously, this promotes the goal of predictability, as investors will know that taxes will be honored.  This predictability encourages investment in multinational companies, as investors are accurately able to calculate their risk, and predict the distributions in event of default.  Additionally, this solution promotes administrative efficiency, as all claims will be able to be dealt with by the home country court, and ancillary or parallel proceedings in foreign courts will not be necessary.  Furthermore, this is the ultimate achievement in fairness, as competing governments, which are similarly situated creditors, are given the same treatment in bankruptcy, and are not discriminated against based on nationality.  Lastly, debtor corporations will be less likely to “forum shop” by moving assets out of countries with large tax claims, as those tax claims will be paid regardless of where the assets actually are located.[38]  On the tax side, such an approach also produces beneficial results.  First, such a policy promotes cooperation and notions of comity, which are beneficial in any area of law,[39] as cooperation leads to increased sharing of burdens and information, which reduces costs for individual nations.[40]  Second, such a policy promotes justice, as it cracks down on would-be tax evaders, and forces them to pay lawful taxes regardless of where the assets may be located.[41]  Lastly, such a policy will protect the national interest, as non-enforcement of taxes would have created a tax burden in the claiming country, which would have to be filled by the rest of the lawful taxpayer base.  

Additionally, this approach ameliorates all of the revenue rule’s concerns.  First, Judge Hand’s concern about judicial embarrassment of other nations is no longer an issue, as judges will not be analyzing foreign tax laws; they will simply be enforcing them.  Second, judicial competence to assess foreign tax law is a non-issue.  Third, separation of powers won’t be an issue, as the enforcement will not be a direct result of judicial action, but will be a result of legislation imposed by the other branches of government, which are permitted to deal in foreign matters.  Lastly, national sovereignty concerns will hopefully be ameliorated through the inducement of reciprocity.[42]  

The obvious potential risk with this approach is that, if adopted unilaterally by the United States, other countries will not adopt the legislation, and will take advantage of the United States.  However, it is likely, due to the acceptance of this issue as a complex and disruptive problem, that many other countries will adopt similar statutes.[43]  The United States should take the first leap and implement this legislation which would provide tremendous advantages to all countries.[44]  Professor Jay Lawrence Westbrook, a staunch supporter of universalism, has noted that “acts of helpful cooperation, without an initial requirement of reciprocity, breed reciprocity,”[45] and Westbrook proves this assertion using examples from section 304, a unilateral statute which was reciprocated by certain foreign governments, despite no reciprocity requirement.[46]  Thus, despite the risk caused by unilateral action, because the goals of bankruptcy and tax law are aligned, the benefits realized by this approach are potentially vast in both disciplines, and it is the best possible solution. 

Solution B: Alternatively, a similar, yet less ambitious, approach would be to mandate universal cross-priority of foreign tax claims, but to require reciprocity—meaning, to only extend the cross-priority privilege to those nations which have adopted a similar provision.  This would solve the major problem of the first approach, in that it would give the United States some leverage in having its own tax claims recognized abroad.[47]  However, there are several problems with including such a requirement,[48] aside from the United States generally disfavoring a reciprocity requirement.[49]  In fact, “[a] reciprocity requirement was debated several times in the [United Nations’ Model Law] discussions because a small number of countries favored it, but it was defeated by a large consensus each time.”[50]  

There are two ways in which a reciprocity requirement could be enforced.[51]  Under the first version, it would be done on an ex post basis, whereby in each insolvency case in which a foreign country has filed a tax claim, the court would analyze the foreign law to determine if it meets the reciprocity requirement.[52]  However, this arrangement would bring about the same “judicial discretion” concerns that the other ex post approaches do; namely, the unpredictability that territorialism brings, and the concerns implicated by the revenue rule.  While the court would not be directly deciding whether to enforce the tax claims, requiring judges to analyze whether a law is, in fact, reciprocal, would “spawn satellite litigation over whether the requirement is satisfied by the foreign country.”[53]  The second method for enforcing a reciprocity requirement analyzes foreign law on an ex ante basis.[54]  Under this approach, the United States government would maintain a list of countries with reciprocal statutes.  This method would remove judicial discretion from the equation, and would force the judiciary to enforce or not enforce a given tax claim.  Thus, this second approach to reciprocity would, in fact, bring about the policy goals of transnational insolvency, in that it would foster ex ante predictability (if only between reciprocal nations), and of taxation, in that no judicial analysis would be necessary.  However, reciprocity requirements, in either of these two forms, have generally not been used in the United States, are not as beneficial to the goals of predictability and cooperation, and are ultimately an unnecessary requirement on the road to universal enforcement.[55]  Nevertheless, if a unilateral mandate cannot be implemented, then a mandate combined with a reciprocity requirement (preferably the second version) would be a compromise worth enacting, as it would be a step toward universal enforcement, and would provide ex ante predictability between reciprocal nations.

Solution C: Lastly, a solution encouraging the United States to enter into treaties mandating the enforcement of foreign tax claims in bankruptcy would reach the same result as an approach mandating the second version of reciprocity.  The result of a treaty approach would be nearly analogous to the previous mandate approach, in that while it is a valid solution and would foster a great deal of cooperation and predictability, the benefits would not be as great as if countries unilaterally decided to grant a universal cross-priority, without regard to reciprocity or treaty.  However, this approach would be substantially more difficult to implement,[56] as it would require significantly more effort, in the form of international cooperation—as opposed to a solution requiring each nation to act unilaterally and to qualify the law with a reciprocity requirement.[57]  In addition, tax treaties in abrogation of the revenue rule have lacked support in the United States.[58]  Thus, this approach, while also mandating reciprocity, would take significantly more effort, and is therefore less likely to be implemented.

The Public Policy Exception
Inevitably, in any potential solution, there must be a “public policy exception,” allowing the home country to refuse to enforce the foreign tax claim if the foreign claim is “manifestly contrary”[59] to the public policy of the home state.[60]   For example, suppose that a rogue nation files a large and dubious tax claim, threatening to consume much of the assets of the insolvent corporation.  Is the home court obligated to honor that claim?  Alternatively, suppose that a friendly, law-abiding nation, otherwise in concert with the United States, has a high tax rate, and is claiming a 95% tax on the corporation’s earnings, in full accordance with its tax laws.  Is the United States to honor such a claim?  These examples illustrate the need for a “public policy exception,” much like the one contained in Section 1506 of the current Bankruptcy Code.  The exception, however, must be given a narrow construction, or it will threaten to eviscerate the entire mandate, and bring the United States, and the world, back to a “discretionary” system, completely void of and predictability and efficiency.  Luckily, there is support for giving public policy exceptions a narrow construction.  Justice Benjamin Cardozo stated that U.S. Courts should not refuse to enforce judgments “unless help would violate some fundamental principle of justice . . .  [or] some deep-rooted tradition of the common weal.”[61]   Another court went even further, requiring a law “repugnant to fundamental notions of what is decent and just.”[62]   The ALI has also subscribed to this notion of narrow construction.[63]  However, despite a narrow interpretation, there are still instances where application of the public policy exception would be necessary.  The first instance, easy to apply, is where the tax claim in question is illegal or corrupt, as in In re Yukos Oil, where over $25 billion in Russian tax claims were deemed by most of the world to be illegal.[64]  Such a claim would clearly be against the public policy of the United States.  The second instance, much more difficult to apply, would be where a country’s tax rate is considered burdensome.  However, this would be a difficult standard to set—would 50% be burdensome?  90%?  100%?  Clearly such rates aren’t illegal, as just 50 years ago the top United States marginal income tax rate was 91%!  At some point, a given tax rate would probably be considered manifestly contrary to the public policy—this standard, though, must be set ex ante, in order to realize the benefits of universalism and to not implicate the revenue rule through excessive discretion.  Short of these two instances, the public policy exception would be rarely used, in order to keep judicial discretion to a minimum, and the mandate to recognize foreign tax claims, whether through Solution A, B, or C, would bring about tax benefits as well as increased efficiency and predictability in all transnational insolvencies. 

Conclusion:
In analyzing the possible solutions, a number of principles are clear:  First, a universal cross-priority system for tax claims, without the need for reciprocity or judicial discretion, accomplishes the goals of transnational insolvency, promotes and furthers the spirit of international cooperation, and minimizes the concerns of the revenue rule while promoting tax goals; Second, in enacting such a system, the public policy exception must be given a narrow interpretation, or else risk rendering the entire law impotent; and third, the issue of reciprocity is the prime concern of the unilateral granting of cross-priority.  Taking into account these ideas, the best solution is for the United States, acting unilaterally, is to mandate the universal cross-priority of tax claims, with a narrow public policy exception, with the hope that similar legislation will be adopted abroad.  The resulting increase in predictability and cooperation will benefit lenders, creditors, governments, and our increasingly global society at large.

1. See John A. E. Pottow, Procedural Incrementalism: A Model for International Bankruptcy, 45 Va. J. Int’l L. 935, 936 (2005) (noting United Airlines, Parmalat and Global Crossing as examples).

2. Id. at 943; Am. Law Inst., Transnational Insolvency Project: Principles of Cooperation in Transnational Insolvency Cases Among Members of the North American Free Trade Agreement 1 (Council Draft, Nov. 24, 1999) [hereinafter ALI Project] (“It has become apparent that traditional legal doctrines and procedures are inadequate to the task of managing a general default across national borders.”).

3. For the differing bankruptcy laws of various countries, see the International Insolvency Institute’s website.  International Insolvency Institute: Country Resources, http://www.iiiglobal.org/e-library/58.

4. U.N. Comm’n on Int’l Trade Law, Draft UNCITRAL Notes on cooperation, communication, and coordination in cross-border insolvency proceedings, Notes by the Secretariat, at 12, U.N. Doc. A/CN.9/WG.V/WP.86 (Mar. 13, 2009).

5. The two universalist approaches accomplish the goals of predictability and the encouragement of foreign investment, as they give the parties involved ex ante foresight as to which country will administer the debtor’s assets.  They also promote administrative efficiency, as fewer proceedings will be opened, and distributive fairness, as similarly situated creditors will be treated the same, regardless of nationality.

6. See, e.g., Liza Perkins, Note, A Defense of Pure Universalism in Cross-Border Corporate Insolvencies, 32 N.Y.U. J. Int’l L. & Pol. 787, 789 (2000) (defining the different approaches to transnational insolvencies).

7. Id.  It should be noted that the actual determination of this “home country” is the subject of much dispute, and has broad ramifications regarding whether the universalist approach is tenable.  The home country is known as the “center of main interests,” or the “COMI.”

8. John J. Chung, The New Chapter 15 of the Bankruptcy Code: A Step Toward Erosion of National Sovereignty, 27 Nw. J. Int’l L. & Bus. 89, 96 (2006).

9. The territorialist approaches promote the protection of local creditors, who may have been subject to a lower priority under foreign law, and the sovereignty of national law, which would be submissive to the foreign law of a debtor’s home country under universalism.

10. Chung, supra note 8, at 93; Lynn M. LoPucki, The Case for Cooperative Territoriality in International Bankruptcy, 98 Mich. L. Rev. 2216, 2218 (2000).

11. Chung, supra note 8, at 93; LoPucki, supra note 10, at 2218.

12. Chung, supra note 8, at 96.

13. Robert K. Rasmussen, Where Are All the Transnational Bankruptcies? The Puzzling Case for Universalism, 32 Brook. J. Int’l L. 983, 983 (2007) (“Universalism is on the march. . . . [t]he tide has seemingly turned [in favor of universalism].”).

14. U.N. Comm’n on Int’l Trade Law, UNCITRAL Model Law on Cross-Border Insolvency With Guide to Enactment, U.N. Doc. A/52/17, U.N. Sales No. E.99.V.3 (1997) [hereinafter the “Model Law”].

15. Council Regulation 1346/00, Insolvency Proceedings, 2000 O.J. (L160) 1 (EC).

16. 11 U.S.C. § 1501 (2006); 11 U.S.C. § 304 (2000) (repealed).

17. William S. Dodge, Breaking the Public Law Taboo, 43 Harv. Int’l L.J. 161, 161 (2002) (“It is common to find judges . . . enforcing a foreign judgment for breach of contract.”).

18. See generally id.

19. E.g. Her Majesty the Queen ex rel. British Columbia v. Gilbertson, 597 F.2d 1161 (9th Cir. 1979).

20. ALI Project, supra note 2, at 117.

21. Model Law, supra note 13, at art. 13, Paragraph 2, n.2.

22. As in the United States.  11 U.S.C. § 507(a)(8) (2006).

23. Cross-priority is the granting by Country X of the same priority that it would give to its own tax claims to Country Y’s tax claims.  See Ulrik Rammeskow Bang-Pederson, Asset Distribution in Transnational Insolvencies: Combining Predictability and Protection of Local Interests, 73 Am. Bankr. L.J. 385, 387 (1999).

24. Jay Lawrence Westbrook, Universal Priorities, 33 Tex. Int’l L.J. 27, 36 (1998) (“The rub is that foreign revenue claims have historically been denied enforcement in all U.S. courts.”).

25. Holman v. Johnson, 98 Eng. Rep. 1120, 1121 (1775) (“No country ever takes notice of the revenue laws of another.”).

26. 597 F.2d 1161 (9th Cir. 1979).

27. Id. at 1162-63.

28. Id. at 1166.  The revenue rule has also been accepted into Restatement (Third) of Foreign Relations Law, which states that “[c]ourts in the United States are not required to recognize or to enforce judgments for the collection of taxes . . . of other states.”  Restatement (Third) of Foreign Relations Law § 483 (2005).

29. Brenda Mallinak, The Revenue Rule: A Common Law Doctrine for the Twenty-First Century, 16 Duke J. Comp. & Int’l L. 79, 88-92 (2006) (bringing examples from Britain, Greece, India, Ireland, and Canada).

30. Dodge, supra note 17, at 220 (quoting Joseph Story, Commentaries on the Conflict of Laws § 620 (1834) (enforcement of tax claims is “[a]n enlightened policy, founded upon national justice, as well as national interest.”).

31. Moore v. Mitchell, 30 F.2d 600, 604 (2d Cir. 1929) (“Thus a scrutiny of the liability is necessarily always in reserve, and the possibility that it will be found not to accord with the policy of the domestic state.”).

32. Kate Kraus, Pasquantino: Foreign Tax Evasion as a Domestic Crime, 32 Corp. Tax’n 03 (2005) (“U.S. judges generally have little experience interpreting foreign law in general, or foreign tax law in particular.”).

33. Dodge, supra note 17, at 176 (quoting Her Majesty the Queen ex rel. British Columbia v. Gilbertson, 597 F.2d 1161, 1165 (9th Cir. 1979) (enforcing foreign tax claims would “have the effect of furthering the governmental interests of a foreign country, something which our courts customarily refuse to do.”)); see also Att’y Gen. of Canada v. R.J. Reynolds Tobacco Holdings, Inc., 268 F.3d 103, 111 (2d Cir. 2001) (“[T]he rule prevents sovereigns from asserting their sovereignty within the borders of other nations, thereby helping nations maintain their mutual respect and security.”).

34. Pasquantino v. United States, 544 U.S. 349, 369 (2005) (stating that the executive is the “sole organ of the federal government in the field of international relations”).

35. Dodge, supra note 17, at 220 (quoting Joseph Story, Commentaries on the Conflict of Laws § 620 (1834) (stating that enforcement of tax claims is “[a]n enlightened policy, founded upon national justice, as well as national interest.”)).

36. Id.

37. This has the potential to cause perverse incentives on the part of foreign countries, who will attempt to force certain corporations into bankruptcy in order to collect taxes which it would otherwise not be able to collect under the revenue rule.

38. Mihailis E. Diamantis, Arbitral Contractualism in Transnational Bankruptcy, 35 Sw. U. L. Rev. 327, 336-37 (“A purely territorialist regime would allow for rampant forum shopping. . . . [T]he debtor has a multiplicity of laws from which to choose.”).

39. Richard W. Hulbert, Some Thoughts on Judgments, Reciprocity, and the Seeming Paradox of International Commercial Arbitration, 29 U. Pa. J. Int’l L. 641, 641 (2008). (“The international enforceability of judgments is, quite reasonably, thought to be relevant to the efficiency of international business.”).

40. Jay Lawrence Westbrook, Theory and Pragmatism in Global Insolvencies: Choice of Law and Choice of Forum, 65 Am. Bankr. L.J. 457, 464-66 (1991) (noting a “transactional gain” that accrues to countries from cooperation in business).

41. While an insolvent corporation isn’t a “tax evader” in the pure sense like an actual individual who crosses national boundaries to reach foreign territory, the idea is the same, that people who owe taxes should pay them regardless of geographic considerations.

42. Dodge, supra note 17, at 219 (arguing that the “sovereignty argument for the public law taboo lead[s] ultimately to reciprocity.  If reciprocal enforcement of a nation’s . . . tax . . . laws could be assured, then such cooperation would be more advantageous to both governments and their citizens than protectionism.”).

43. Jay Lawrence Westbrook, Multinational Enterprises in General Default: Chapter 15, The ALI Principles, and the EU Insolvency Regulation, 76 Am. Bankr. L.J. 1, 29 (2002) (“The experience in the United States . . . is that helpful and cooperative actions . . .  produce reciprocal assistance from courts in other countries.”).

44. For a judicial view on the hesitation to require reciprocity, see Cunard Steamship Co. Ltd. v. Salen Reefer Servs. AB, 773 F.2d 452, 460 (2d Cir. 1985) (“[W]hile reciprocity may be a factor to be considered, it is not required as a condition precedent to the granting of comity.”).

45. Westbrook, supra note 43, at 29.  See also Jay L. Westbrook, Transnational Bankruptcies (Pre-Publication Draft), AALS Workshop on Bankruptcy, available athttp://www.aals.org/profdev/bankruptcy/westbrook1.pdf (“This unilateral initiative did not require reciprocity and did not attract much reciprocity at first . . . . More recently other countries have began to move in the direction of cooperation . . . .”).

46. Westbrook, supra note 43, at 29 (citing Roberts v. Picture Butte Mun. Hosp., [1999] 4 W.W.R. 443 (Canadian court recognizes a U.S. court as the best court for the case in the interest of international comity); Barclays Bank plc v. Homan (In re Maxwell Communication Corp.), [1992] B.C.C. 757 (Ch.) (Homan), aff’d, [1992] B.C.C. 767 (C.A.) (noting a British court’s recognition of U.S. action even when most parties were British)).

47. Hulbert, supra note 39, at 653.

48. Reciprocity and the Recognition of Foreign Judgments, 36 Yale L.J. 542, 547 (1927) (“Reciprocity has been bitterly criticized.  The criticism generally takes the form of comparing it disadvantageously with a theory of universal recognition of foreign judgments.”).

49. Dodge, supra note 17, at 227-28 (stating that most U.S. states adopting the Uniform Money Judgments Recognition Act have not included a reciprocity requirement, and that numerous Restatements do not require it).

50. Westbrook, supra note 43, at 29.

51. Susan L. Stevens, Note, Commanding International Judicial Respect: Reciprocity and the Recognition and Enforcement of Foreign Judgments, 26 Hastings Int’l & Comp. L. Rev. 115, 131 (2002) (citing International Jurisdiction and Judgments Project, ALI Council Draft No. 1, at Summary (Nov. 20, 2001)).

52. Id.

53. Hulbert, supra note 39, at 651.

54. Id.

55. Westbrook, supra note 43.

56. Jenny Clift, The UNCITRAL Model Law on Cross-Border Insolvency—A Legislative Framework to Facilitate Coordination and Cooperation in Cross-Border Insolvency, 12 Tul. J. Int’l & Comp. L. 307, 312 (2004) (“There has also been a lack of multilateral treaty arrangements.”).

57. Id. (“[T]he effort to negotiate such agreements is generally substantial . . . .”).

58. Mallinak, supra note 29, at 97 (discussing the “vitality of the revenue rule”).

59. The idea of the public policy exception, as well as the language excepting only cases which are “manifestly” contrary to public policy, is borrowed from Chapter 15.  11 U.S.C. § 1506.

60. Karen E. Minehan, The Public Policy Exception to the Enforcement of Foreign Judgments: Necessary or Nemesis? 18 Loy. L.A. Int’l & Comp. L.J. 795, 817-18 (1996). (“The public policy exception is an essential political tool to encourage [states to enforce foreign law] because it serves as a ‘safety valve’ for unforeseeable changes in the law.”).

61. Loucks v. Standard Oil Co. of New York, 120 N.E. 198, 202 (N.Y. 1918).

62. Tahan v. Hodgson, 662 F.2d 862, 866 (D.C. Cir. 1981) (enforcing an Israeli default judgment which would not have been enforced under United States law).

63. Am. Law Inst., International Jurisdiction and Judgments Project, Report, at 27 (Apr. 14, 2000) (“We are committed to a narrow interpretation of the public-policy defense to recognition . . . .”).

64. In re Yukos Oil Co., 321 B.R. 396 (Bankr. S.D. Tex. 2005). 

 

View Online.